Published in Ayn Rand's "Objectivist" newsletter in 1966, and reprinted in her book, Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal, in 1967.
Gold & Economic Freedom
By Alan Greenspan
By Alan Greenspan
An almost hysterical antagonism toward the gold
standard is one issue which unites statists of all persuasions. They
seem to sense — perhaps more clearly and subtly than many consistent
defenders of laissez-faire — that gold and economic freedom are
inseparable, that the gold standard is an instrument of laissez-faire
and that each implies and requires the other.
In order to understand the source of their
antagonism, it is necessary first to understand the specific role of
gold in a free society.
~~~
Money is the common denominator of all economic transactions.
~~~
Money is the common denominator of all economic transactions.
It is that commodity which serves as a medium of
exchange, is universally acceptable to all participants in an exchange
economy as payment for their goods or services, and can, therefore, be
used as a standard of market value and as a store of value, i.e., as a
means of saving.
Picture
The existence of such a commodity is a precondition of a division of labor economy. If men did not have some commodity of objective value which was generally acceptable as money, they would have to resort to primitive barter or be forced to live on self-sufficient farms and forgo the inestimable advantages of specialization. If men had no means to store value, i.e., to save, neither long-range planning nor exchange would be possible.
The existence of such a commodity is a precondition of a division of labor economy. If men did not have some commodity of objective value which was generally acceptable as money, they would have to resort to primitive barter or be forced to live on self-sufficient farms and forgo the inestimable advantages of specialization. If men had no means to store value, i.e., to save, neither long-range planning nor exchange would be possible.
What medium of exchange will be acceptable to
all participants in an economy is not determined arbitrarily. First, the
medium of exchange should be durable.
In a primitive society of meager wealth, wheat
might be sufficiently durable to serve as a medium, since all exchanges
would occur only during and immediately after the harvest, leaving no
value-surplus to store. But where store-of-value considerations are
important, as they are in richer, more civilized societies, the medium
of exchange must be a durable commodity, usually a metal.
A metal is generally chosen because it is
homogeneous and divisible: every unit is the same as every other and it
can be blended or formed in any quantity. Precious jewels, for example,
are neither homogeneous nor divisible. More important, the commodity
chosen as a medium must be a luxury.
Human desires for luxuries are unlimited and,
therefore, luxury goods are always in demand and will always be
acceptable. Wheat is a luxury in underfed civilizations, but not in a
prosperous society.
Cigarettes ordinarily would not serve as money,
but they did in post-World War II Europe where they were considered a
luxury. The term "luxury good" implies scarcity and high unit value.
Having a high unit value, such a good is easily portable; for instance,
an ounce of gold is worth a half-ton of pig iron.
In the early stages of a developing money
economy, several media of exchange might be used, since a wide variety
of commodities would fulfill the foregoing conditions. However, one of
the commodities will gradually displace all others, by being more widely
acceptable.
Preferences on what to hold as a store of value
will shift to the most widely acceptable commodity, which, in turn, will
make it still more acceptable. The shift is progressive until that
commodity becomes the sole medium of exchange.
The use of a single medium is highly
advantageous for the same reasons that a money economy is superior to a
barter economy: it makes exchanges possible on an incalculably wider
scale.
Whether the single medium is gold, silver,
seashells, cattle, or tobacco is optional, depending on the context and
development of a given economy. In fact, all have been employed, at
various times, as media of exchange. Even in the present century, two
major commodities, gold and silver, have been used as international
media of exchange, with gold becoming the predominant one.
Gold, having both artistic and functional uses
and being relatively scarce, has significant advantages over all other
media of exchange. Since the beginning of World War I, it has been
virtually the sole international standard of exchange.
If all goods and services were to be paid for in
gold, large payments would be difficult to execute and this would tend
to limit the extent of a society's divisions of labor and
specialization.
Thus a logical extension of the creation of a
medium of exchange is the development of a banking system and credit
instruments (bank notes and deposits) which act as a substitute for, but
are convertible into, gold.
A free banking system based on gold is able to
extend credit and thus to create bank notes (currency) and deposits,
according to the production requirements of the economy. Individual
owners of gold are induced, by payments of interest, to deposit their
gold in a bank (against which they can draw checks).
But since it is rarely the case that all
depositors want to withdraw all their gold at the same time, the banker
need keep only a fraction of his total deposits in gold as reserves.
This enables the banker to loan out more than
the amount of his gold deposits (which means that he holds claims to
gold rather than gold as security of his deposits). But the amount of loans
which he can afford to make is not arbitrary: he has to gauge it in
relation to his reserves and to the status of his investments.
When banks loan money to finance productive and profitable endeavors, the loans are paid off rapidly and bank credit continues to be generally available.
But when the business ventures financed by bank credit are less profitable and slow to pay off, bankers soon find that their loans
outstanding are excessive relative to their gold reserves, and they
begin to curtail new lending, usually by charging higher interest rates.
This tends to restrict the financing of new
ventures and requires the existing borrowers to improve their
profitability before they can obtain credit for further expansion. Thus,
under the gold standard, a free banking system stands as the protector
of an economy's stability and balanced growth.
When gold is accepted as the medium of exchange
by most or all nations, an unhampered free international gold standard
serves to foster a world-wide division of labor and the broadest
international trade.
Even though the units of exchange (the dollar,
the pound, the franc, etc.) differ from country to country, when all are
defined in terms of gold the economies of the different countries act
as one — so long as there are no restraints on trade or on the movement
of capital.
Credit, interest rates, and prices tend to
follow similar patterns in all countries. For example, if banks in one
country extend credit too liberally, interest rates in that country will
tend to fall, inducing depositors to shift their gold to
higher-interest paying banks in other countries.
This will immediately cause a shortage of bank
reserves in the "easy money" country, inducing tighter credit standards
and a return to competitively higher interest rates again.
A fully free banking system and fully consistent
gold standard have not as yet been achieved. But prior to World War I,
the banking system in the United States (and in most of the world) was
based on gold and even though governments intervened occasionally,
banking was more free than controlled. Periodically, as a result of
overly rapid credit expansion, banks became loaned up to the limit of
their gold reserves, interest rates rose sharply, new credit was cut
off, and the economy went into a sharp, but short-lived recession.
(Compared with the depressions of 1920 and 1932,
the pre-World War I business declines were mild indeed.) It was limited
gold reserves that stopped the unbalanced expansions of business
activity, before they could develop into the post-World War I type of
disaster. The readjustment periods were short and the economies quickly
reestablished a sound basis to resume expansion.
But the process of cure was misdiagnosed as the
disease: if shortage of bank reserves was causing a business decline —
argued economic interventionists — why not find a way of supplying
increased reserves to the banks so they never need be short! If banks
can continue to loan money indefinitely — it was claimed — there need
never be any slumps in business.
And so the Federal Reserve System was organized in 1913.
It consisted of twelve regional Federal Reserve
banks nominally owned by private bankers, but in fact government
sponsored, controlled, and supported. Credit extended by these banks is
in practice (though not legally) backed by the taxing power of the
federal government.
Technically, we remained on the gold standard;
individuals were still free to own gold, and gold continued to be used
as bank reserves. But now, in addition to gold, credit extended by the
Federal Reserve banks ("paper reserves") could serve as legal tender to
pay depositors.
When business in the United States underwent a
mild contraction in 1927, the Federal Reserve created more paper
reserves in the hope of forestalling any possible bank reserve shortage.
More disastrous, however, was the Federal
Reserve's attempt to assist Great Britain who had been losing gold to us
because the Bank of England refused to allow interest rates to rise
when market forces dictated (it was politically unpalatable).
The reasoning of the authorities involved was as
follows: if the Federal Reserve pumped excessive paper reserves into
American banks, interest rates in the United States would fall to a
level comparable with those in Great Britain; this would act to stop
Britain's gold loss and avoid the political embarrassment of having to
raise interest rates.
The "Fed" succeeded; it stopped the gold loss,
but it nearly destroyed the economies of the world, in the process. The
excess credit which the Fed pumped into the economy spilled over into
the stock market, triggering a fantastic speculative boom.
Belatedly, Federal Reserve officials attempted
to sop up the excess reserves and finally succeeded in braking the boom.
But it was too late: by 1929 the speculative imbalances had become so
overwhelming that the attempt precipitated a sharp retrenching and a
consequent demoralizing of business confidence.
As a result, the American economy collapsed.
Great Britain fared even worse, and rather than absorb the full
consequences of her previous folly, she abandoned the gold standard
completely in 1931, tearing asunder what remained of the fabric of
confidence and inducing a world-wide series of bank failures. The world
economies plunged into the Great Depression of the 1930's.
With a logic reminiscent of a generation
earlier, statists argued that the gold standard was largely to blame for
the credit debacle which led to the Great Depression.
If the gold standard had not existed, they
argued, Britain's abandonment of gold payments in 1931 would not have
caused the failure of banks all over the world. (The irony was that
since 1913, we had been, not on a gold standard, but on what may be
termed "a mixed gold standard"; yet it is gold that took the blame.)
But the opposition to the gold standard in any
form — from a growing number of welfare-state advocates — was prompted
by a much subtler insight: the realization that the gold standard is
incompatible with chronic deficit spending (the hallmark of the welfare
state).
Stripped of its academic jargon, the welfare
state is nothing more than a mechanism by which governments confiscate
the wealth of the productive members of a society to support a wide
variety of welfare schemes. A substantial part of the confiscation is
effected by taxation.
But the welfare statists were quick to recognize
that if they wished to retain political power, the amount of taxation
had to be limited and they had to resort to programs of massive deficit
spending, i.e., they had to borrow money, by issuing government bonds,
to finance welfare expenditures on a large scale.
Under a gold standard, the amount of credit that
an economy can support is determined by the economy's tangible assets,
since every credit instrument is ultimately a claim on some tangible
asset. But government bonds are not backed by tangible wealth, only by
the government's promise to pay out of future tax revenues, and cannot
easily be absorbed by the financial markets.
A large volume of new government bonds can be sold to the public only at progressively higher interest rates. Thus, government deficit spending under a gold standard is severely limited.
A large volume of new government bonds can be sold to the public only at progressively higher interest rates. Thus, government deficit spending under a gold standard is severely limited.
The abandonment of the gold standard made it
possible for the welfare statists to use the banking system as a means
to an unlimited expansion of credit.
They have created paper reserves in the form of
government bonds which — through a complex series of steps — the banks
accept in place of tangible assets and treat as if they were an actual
deposit, i.e., as the equivalent of what was formerly a deposit of gold.
The holder of a government bond or of a bank
deposit created by paper reserves believes that he has a valid claim on a
real asset. But the fact is that there are now more claims outstanding
than real assets. The law of supply and demand is not to be conned.
As the supply of money (of claims) increases
relative to the supply of tangible assets in the economy, prices must
eventually rise. Thus the earnings saved by the productive members of
the society lose value in terms of goods.
When the economy's books are finally balanced,
one finds that this loss in value represents the goods purchased by the
government for welfare or other purposes with the money proceeds of the
government bonds financed by bank credit expansion.
In the absence of the gold standard, there is no
way to protect savings from confiscation through inflation. There is no
safe store of value. If there were, the government would have to make
its holding illegal, as was done in the case of gold.
If everyone decided, for example, to convert all
his bank deposits to silver or copper or any other good, and thereafter
declined to accept checks as payment for goods, bank deposits would
lose their purchasing power and government-created bank credit would be
worthless as a claim on goods. The financial policy of the welfare state
requires that there be no way for the owners of wealth to protect
themselves.
This is the shabby secret of the welfare
statists' tirades against gold. Deficit spending is simply a scheme for
the confiscation of wealth. Gold stands in the way of this insidious
process. It stands as a protector of property rights. If one grasps
this, one has no difficulty in understanding the statists' antagonism
toward the gold standard.
Original URL: http://www.constitution.org/mon/greenspan_gold.htm | Text Version
2 comments:
THIS GEREENPUKE IS ON THE FIRST TO BE ARRESTED LIST....FOR THOSE WHO DO NOT KNOW HE WAS THE PIECE OF CRAPPOLA THAT WAS THE HEAD OF THE FED BEFORE BENNY BOY BERNANKE..... HE NEEDS TO BE ARRESTED AND GIVEN A JOB AS A ROPE STRETCHER....
Hold your breath until that arrest, or any other arrest, happens.....
Post a Comment